美国的
货币政策的制定和执行职责,长期以来由美国的中央银行即
美国联邦储备委员会(简称
美联储,FRS)承担。货币政策是美国调控
国民经济和
社会发展的主要宏观
政策工具。
美国法律规定,货币政策的目标是实现充分就业并保持市值的稳定,创造一个相对稳定的
金融环境。在货币政策执行过程中,美联储积极运用有关
金融工具以尽量减少利率和货币信贷量的变化,努力达到兼顾 “充分就业、市值稳定”的两大目标的目的。随着
市场经济的成熟和发展,美联储货币政策在宏观调控经济方面发挥了日益重要的作用。
调控思想
调控的思想是逆
经济风险行事,衰退时降低
准备率和
再贴现率,公开市场买入;繁荣时则反过来操作。
准备金制度原本为了保障商业银行的流动性,后来演变成控制商业银行
信用创造的工具。
美国货币政策的实质是服务于本国经济,美联储深刻理解美国资产泡沫是美国多年扩张的货币造成的,主观上希望泡沫永远不会破裂,另一方面通过微调美国经济、消化历史包袱。
调控效果
货币政策的运用存在着认识
时滞、决策时滞和生效时滞,然后使得正确的政策在错误的时间发生作用,不是“熨平”,而是扩大经济的
波幅。30年代的大危机据说就是货币政策的失误造成,90年代初格利斯潘的调控实践也不很成功。
二战传导机制
1、40-50年代初。1941年,
美联储为筹措
军费,采取了廉价的
货币政策,即钉住战前的低利率:三个月期的国库券利率为0.375%,长期财政债券利率2.4%。无论什么时候,只要
利率上升到高于上述水平,而且
债券价格开始下跌时,美联储就进行
公开市场购买,迫使利率下降。这一政策在大部分时间内是成功的,但当1950年
朝鲜战争爆发时,引起了通货膨胀。1951年3月,美联储和财政部达成“一致协议”,取消钉住利率,但美联储承诺它将不让利率急剧上升。同时,美联储正式独立于财政部,此后货币政策才开始具有完全的独立性,这也标志着美国货币政策开始成为影响
美国经济的主导力量。
2、50-70年代。这期间美国经济周期性扩张和收缩的特征非常突出,因此,
扩张性货币政策和紧缩性的货币政策交替也很明显,货币政策目标经常变化。50年代,美联储控制的中介指标有自由
储备金净额、三个月期的国库券利率和
货币总量比,并按此次序来决定指标控制的重要性。结果表明,美联储对前两个指标的控制较好,对货币
总量控制较差,这导致最初的10年内竞发生了三次
经济危机。到了60年代,又重新推行廉价的货币政策,同时重视
财政政策的运用。
货币供应量的
增长率日趋上升,松的货币政策加之松的财政政策导致
通货膨胀率不断上升,从1965年的2.3%到1969年的6.1%。这些政策进一步导致了70年代滞胀的发生。70年代,美联储将货币总量作为中间目标,从
M1 和
M2的增长率来看,美联储以紧缩的货币政策为主,最终导致了1979年的经济危机。
3、80-90年代。70年代后,随着通货膨胀被抑制,美联储又转向了平稳
利率政策,并获得了极大成功。例如90年代初,美国经济陷入萧条,美联储在1990年7月到1992年9月间连续逐步降息17次,将
短期利率从8%降到3%,促进投资与消费上升,从而带动了整个经济的发展。在1994年到1995年7月,美国
经济过热时,又连续7次提高联邦基金利率,成功地实现了软着陆。1994年美联储主席格林斯潘指出,美联储将放弃以货币供应量的增减对经济实行宏观调控的做法,今后将以调控
实际利率作为
经济调控的主要手段。这标志着美国货币政策的
重大转变。
4、自1999年6月开始,为防止经济过热,美联储开始抽紧银根,半年中先后三次提高利率。但美国
经济增长势头仍没有减缓的迹象,于是在2000年2月2日、3月21日和5月16日又分别提高利率,使联邦基金利率达到65%。5月底公布的数据表明力度加大的宏观调控开始见效,经济增长逐步放缓。但2001年伊始,种种迹象表明,美国经济已进入了明显放慢的敏感时期。为刺激经济回升,从1月至6月底,美联储连续六次降息。在这么短的时间内采取如此大的降息动作,是近20年来的第一次。美国联邦基金利率和
贴现率分别为3.75%和3.25%,均为7年多来的最低水平。美联储表示,美国经济今后一段时期面临的主要危险仍是疲软,这意味着美联储可能还会降息。虽然美国经济还没有明显好转的迹象,但大多数经济学家认为,下半年美国
经济形势将会出现好转。因为,首先,利率调整通常需要6至9个月的时间才能对经济产生全面影响。这意味着美联储开始的降息行动将在下半年充分发挥作用。其次,布什政府已开始实施其大规模减税计划。根据这一计划,美国家庭下半年可获得450亿美元的减税。再次,美国的消费者信心已开始回升,个人消费开支可望继续增加。
经济发展
从美联储提供的1971呈2001年美国GDP增长、生产力水平和物价
走势图可以看出:90年代中后期是美国经济最活跃的时期,在此期间,美国经济持续保持高速增长,
通货膨胀率也控制在较低幅度,生产力水平的增长超过了30年的平均水平。在美国过去十年经济高速增长时期,一个很显著的特征是各类
投资基金发展迅速。
风险投资基金的发展,有力支持了
新兴企业特别是高科技企业不断成长壮大;
并购基金的发展,加快了企业的
兼并重组,使一大批企业加快转型步伐,更多的由传统行业转向半导体、电信、信息技术等
新兴产业,居民及企业投资意愿旺盛。
随着经济快速增长,1998年以来,美国经济也不同程度上出现投资过度、投机增加等泡沫
经济现象,一些新兴企业股价被严重高估,如从事
信息网络业务的亚马逊公司的
股票市值在一段时间竟与通用公司的市值几乎相当,严重背离了实际情况。为了防止经济进一步过热,美联储在两年曾连续7次提高
贷款利息,促使市场修正过热的
经济预期,导致
美国股市回落,
企业投资特别是
高新技术领域投资明显下降,经济增长逐步趋缓。
2000年第四季度开始,美国经济增长出现停滞之势。2000年以来,为了防止经济衰退,提升企业和个人投资意愿,促进经济增长,尤其是振兴 “9·1l”事件后遭受重大打击的美国经济,美联储又连续11次降息,
美元一年期浮动利率从原来的6.5%下降到1.75%,以刺激
居民消费和投资的增长。美联储有关官员认为:从近30年来美国生产力水平
曲线图可以看出,这次美国经济衰退与历史上其他时期的经济衰退有所不同。由于美国生产力水平仍保持在基本高于平均增长值状况,竞争力仍属较高水平,因此美国经济有望在开始复苏,并逐步进入新一轮增长。
货币政策目标
Judd, Rudebusch
下面是一封旧金山联邦储备银行的经济学通信。里面谈到了美国的货币政策目标及其历史演变。1913年,美联储成立的时候,没有规定目标,只说它的作用是维持货币弹性。1946年《就业法》规定美联储的货币政策目标是促进最大就业。1977年和1978年的《全面就业和预算平衡法》规定,货币政策有三个:“完全就业,
价格稳定,中
长期利率平稳”。正在争论是否将货币政策目标只减为保持价格稳定这一项。欧洲央行已经这样做了。
================[/title5]
FRBSF Economic Letter
99-04; January 29, 1999
The Goals of
U.S. Monetary Policy
* The evolution of the Fed's legislative mandate * The debate about the Fed's current mandate * References
The Federal Reserve has seen its legislative mandate for monetary policy change several times since its founding in 1913, when macroeconomic policy as such was not clearly understood. The most recent revisions were in 1977 and 1978, and they require the Fed to promote both price stability and full employment. The past changes in the mandate appear to reflect both economic events in the U.S. and advances in understanding how the economy functions. In the twenty years since the Fed's mandate was last changed, there have been further important economic developments
as well as refinements in economic thought, and these raise the issue of whether to modify the goals for U.S. monetary policy once again. Indeed, a number of other countries--notably those that adopted the Euro as a common curency at the start of this year--have accepted price stability as the new primary goal for their monetary policies.
In this Letter, we spell out the evolution of the legislation governing U.S. monetary policy goals and summarize the debate about whether they could be improved.
The evolution of the Fed's legislative mandate
intact from the 1946 Employment Act;
however The debate about the Fed's current mandate
The Fed then has two main legislated goals for monetary policy: promoting full employment and promoting stable prices. With this mandate, the Fed has helped foster the exceptional performance of the U.S. economy during the past decade. Still, some have argued that the Fed's mandate could be improved, especially in looking ahead to future attempts to maintain or institutionalize recent low inflation. Much discussion has centered on two topics: the transparency of the goals and their dual nature.
The transparency of goals refers to the extent to which the objectives of monetary policy are clearly defined and can be easily and obviously understood by the public. The goal of full employment will never be very transparent because it is not directly observed but only estimated by economists with limited precision. For example, the 1997 Economic Report of the President (which has authority in this matter from the Humphrey-Hawkins Act) gives a range of 5 to 6% for the unemployment rate consistent with full employment, with a midpoint of 5.5%. Research suggests that there is a very wide range of
uncertainty around any estimate of the natural rate, with one prominent study finding a 95% probability that it falls in the wide range of 4 to 7-1/2 % (see Walsh 1998).
Price stability as a goal is also subject to some ambiguity. Recent economic analysis has uncovered systematic biases, say, on the order of 1 percentage point, in the CPI's measurement of inflation (see Motley 1997). In this case, actual price stability would be consistent with measured inflation of 1%. In addition, at any point in time, different price indexes register different rates of inflation. Over the past year, for example, the CPI has risen about 1-1/2%, while the GDP price index has risen about 1%. Still, a transparent price stability goal could be specified as a precise numerical growth rate (or range) for a particular index (which could take into account any biases). However, economists have also suggested other ways to enhance the transparency of policy. For example, publishing medium-term inflation forecasts might help to clarify the direction of policy (Rudebusch and Walsh 1998). Because the central bank has some control over inflation in the medium term, its forecasts would contain an indication of where it wanted inflation to go.
Economists remain divided on the importance of the time inconsistency problem and on the need to put primary emphasis on price stability at the expense of output stabilization. Some stress the fact that the central bank is the only entity that can guarantee price stability, and that this goal is not likely to be attained for long unless price stability is designated as the primary goal. Others find the arguments for time inconsistency implausible because policymakers, who are aware of the arguments about an inflationary bias and see the implications for inflation, can conduct policy without an inflationary bias (McCallum 1995). Still others argue that the abdication of other goals is irresponsible (Fuhrer 1997). Also, a good deal of empirical research using simulations of models of the U.S. economy suggests that a focus on dual goals can reduce the variance of real GDP (i.e., smooth the business cycle) while achieving an inflation goal as well (Rudebusch and Svensson 1998).
While these issues are not yet resolved, the experience of the past two decades provides some support to those who think dual goals that lack transparency can function successfully. It is true that some countries around the world have reduced inflation over this period while putting primary emphasis on explicit inflation targeting. But at the same time, with its current legislative mandate, the Fed also has had success in reducing inflation, while maintaining the flexibility of responding to business cycle conditions.
John P. Judd Vice President and Associate Director of Research
Glenn D. Rudebusch Research Officer References
大事记